top of page
Writer's pictureFIC Hansraj

Havoc Amidst Harmony: Navigating the Tragedy of the Commons

In a world of shared resources, consumers often act like curious children in a candy store, unaware of limits. Imagine a bustling fair, everyone grabbing cotton candy without thinking about the supply. But, reality asks: Is there enough sweetness for everyone?




Let's start with a small-scale scenario to answer this question. Imagine there are three fishermen sharing one pond, which initially has six fish. Each day, every pair of fish in the pond gives birth to one new fish. So, what's the maximum number of fish they should catch daily? It can't exceed three, one for each fisherman, because every day, three new fish are added. This way, the pond's fish population can remain stable or even grow as long as no more than three fish are caught each day.

However, the sad reality is that "enough" is a concept often overlooked. People often act in their own self-interest without considering the consequences for others. For instance, if one of the fishermen decided to catch two fish daily, the fish population would decline. In the long run (in our example, three days), they would deplete the fish entirely. This scenario is a classic example of what we call the "tragedy of the commons."


No Matter How Many Fish in the Sea

The Tragedy of the Commons, a concept rooted in shared-resource systems, illustrates how rational individuals, acting in self-interest, can ultimately deplete communal resources, leading to negative consequences for all. Economically, individuals tend to exploit shared resources so that demand outweighs supply and it becomes unavailable for all. Hence, personal short-term gains can lead to shared long-term losses.

But would this apply to all the resources which exist?

To explore this let us consider a private orchard owned by a single family. The fruits from the trees are exclusive to the family; outsiders cannot access them without permission (excludable). The orchard is carefully tended, ensuring an abundance of fruits each year (non-scarce). The family members share responsibilities, ensuring the orchard's health and productivity (non-rivalrous). In this scenario, the tragedy of the commons does not occur. It occurs when each consumer consumes as much as they can as fast as they can before others deplete the good, and no one has the incentive to reinvest in maintaining or reproducing the good. The tragedy of the commons occurs when an economic resource possesses specific traits: it must be both rivalrous (only one person can use it at a time, depleting supply) and non-excludable (others can't be prevented from using it). Additionally, it must be scarce to be rivalrous. When a good is a common pool resource, shared by all but limited in quantity, the tragedy emerges as individual interests clash with the common good. The orchard's controlled access, abundance, and lack of rivalry in consumption prevent overuse, allowing the resource to thrive without depletion.


The Tragedy of Speculative Bubbles

The tragedy of the commons can also play in the pond of financial markets as it manifests vividly in the form of speculative bubbles. Imagine a scenario where a particular asset, say housing or cryptocurrencies, experiences a rapid surge in value. This uptick often triggers a collective frenzy among investors. Driven by the fear of missing out on potential profits, individual investors pour their funds into these assets, akin to multiple consumers exploiting a common-pool resource.


During a speculative bubble, the market becomes a shared resource. Just as multiple users can deplete a common pool resource, a multitude of investors rush to buy into the rising market. Each investor believes they can capitalise on the asset's momentum, adding to the demand and inflating prices further. This collective behaviour mirrors the tragedy of the commons: everyone competes for the same unit of the asset, and each transaction contributes to the diminishing supply of the asset at its current price.


However, the tragedy unfolds when the bubble inevitably bursts. As investors rush to sell their holdings to secure profits, the market experiences a sharp downturn. This sudden collective action to sell further accelerates the fall in prices. Ultimately, the rush to exit the market mirrors the depletion of a common-pool resource, leaving many investors with substantial losses.

Global Odyssey

The tragedy of the commons manifests in various spheres, notably in international relations, where the overfishing crisis in global waters symbolizes the struggle over shared resources. Unregulated exploitation by multiple nations often leads to resource depletion and international disputes. In the financial realm, this tragedy is evident in speculative bubbles where investors, lured by potential profits, collectively inflate asset values, risking market stability. Regulatory bodies such as India's Securities and Exchange Board (SEBI) and the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) work tirelessly to curb such behaviours and prevent market crashes. Intellectual property, especially in open-source software, mirrors this challenge as voluntary contributions risk mismanagement without proper oversight. Creative Commons licenses offer a structured solution, balancing collaboration and protection. The tragedy resonates on a grand scale in international resource management; individual interests drive nations to deplete resources like forests and water basins, impacting the global environment. International agreements, such as the Paris Agreement on climate change, strive to mitigate these challenges through cooperative efforts. Additionally, shared forests face depletion from unchecked logging, necessitating robust management strategies to prevent overuse. This underscores the tragedy's significance in environmental conservation efforts worldwide.


Resources on the Brink

The tragedy of the commons poses a significant risk of resource extinction. When a resource is exploited without restraint due to its rivalrous and non-excludable nature, it faces rapid depletion. Overfishing, deforestation, and pollution exemplify this risk, leading to biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse. As individual interests clash with the common good, the overuse of these shared resources accelerates their decline, ultimately risking their extinction. This perilous scenario underscores the urgent need for sustainable management, global cooperation, and stringent regulations to mitigate the tragedy of the commons. Without such measures, the depletion of essential resources becomes inevitable, posing severe threats to ecosystems, wildlife, and the well-being of future generations.


Maintaining the Balance

In our pursuit of sustainable futures, the prevention of the tragedy of the commons stands as a fundamental imperative, ensuring both the preservation of precious resources and the stability of financial systems. Particularly in finance, stringent regulations and investor education are vital. Regulations must curtail speculative excesses and promote responsible investment, fostering market integrity. Transparent practices and comprehensive investor education can shift the focus from short-term gains to long-term stability, promoting financial sustainability. Simultaneously, global cooperation, technological innovation, and sustainable practices are essential in conserving natural resources. Collaborative efforts among nations can manage vital common-pool resources, while innovations in technology enhance resource efficiency. Sustainable practices, embraced by communities and industries, mitigate the overuse and depletion of shared resources. By striking a balance between individual interests and the collective good, societies can navigate these challenges, ensuring a future where resources are conserved, financial systems are stable, and prosperity is sustainable.


Sources: Garret Hardin, Tragedy of the Commons, 13 Dec 1968

Harvard Business School Investopedia


Author: Priyansh Kotiya

Illustrator: Prateek Verma


Commentaires


bottom of page